Standard content for Members only
To continue reading this article, please login to your Utility Week account, Start 14 day trial or Become a member.
If your organisation already has a corporate membership and you haven’t activated it simply follow the register link below. Check here.
Decc seems to be saying that competition can deliver a lot, but not energy efficiency schemes through Eco, says Peter Broad.
Competition in the energy market can achieve a lot, but it cannot achieve efficient delivery of energy efficiency schemes through the Energy Company Obligation (Eco). That appeared to be the message from the Department of Energy and Climate Change at the Energy and Climate Change select committee this month.
The rationale behind a supplier obligation like Eco is that market forces will ensure efficient delivery. Yet, at the committee, a Decc official confirmed it cut Eco because of pressure from those suppliers that had been uncompetitive in delivering their obligation.
There was a big gap between the highest and lowest cost suppliers, and it is now clear it was those with higher costs that lobbied for the scheme to be revised. If the issue was high costs for certain suppliers, rather than high costs across the board, it begs the question: why did the government not let competitive pressures play out? Is that not the whole point of obligating the suppliers to deliver Eco?
There are three possible explanations. They are not mutually exclusive and all are likely to have played a part.
The first is that Eco distorts the market for energy suppliers’ core business: buying and selling gas and electricity. Under this system, an otherwise excellent supplier
that happens to be terrible at delivering energy efficiency will be forced to raise its prices, eventually going out of business, and depriving consumers of the choice of that company. This is a plausible argument but not one Decc has been making. After all, while the review has reduced the size of Eco, the supplier obligation has not been fundamentally challenged.
The second relates to the broader issue of lack of competition in the retail market, which is linked to customer inertia in the face of a system that discourages switching. The impending Competition and Markets Authority (CMA) inquiry is the latest response to this. If competition in the supply market is flawed, then it is illogical to rely on this market dynamic to ensure that policies like Eco or, for that matter, the smart meter roll-out, are delivered cost effectively.
For both these reasons it is crucial that the CMA inquiry covers Eco alongside the mainstream market issues.
Finally, the change shows that suppliers have been able to exploit a lack of political commitment. It appears some companies find it easier – by leaning on Decc – to adapt the regulatory environment to accommodate their lack of competitiveness than they do to adapt their behaviour in response to competitive pressure. This creates political risk for all market participants, which will ultimately increase costs for consumers.
When setting the policy, did Decc consider how it would respond to the pressure that would inevitably come from inefficient suppliers?
The solution for Eco is relatively simple: take responsibility for energy efficiency schemes away from suppliers. If Decc is going to lose its bottle in the face of pressure from suppliers, any efficiency benefits from such a model will evaporate.
If distribution networks were given the obligation it could be made to work alongside incentives to reduce demand across their networks. By contrast, there is a widely acknowledged tension in asking suppliers to reduce demand for their own product. Taking responsibility for the delivery away from suppliers would also facilitate the roll-out of a local delivery model, which research suggests is the cheapest way of delivering energy efficiency.
More preferable still would be to move the cost of energy efficiency off energy bills, which is notoriously regressive, and on to general taxation.
The broader issues of competition and political risk are more complex and will be more difficult to solve. But we should start by recognising the possibility of their existence. And, when designing policy, government policy-makers need to be clear about the limits of what competition can achieve.
Peter Broad, policy manager,
Consumer Futures
Please login or Register to leave a comment.